Thursday, February 2, 2012

Super Bowl Predictions!




U.S AMASSeco: Lab of Google or Hoax!Supporting Biofuels Prices without Taxes or Subsidies – a Biofuels Digest special report

| June 9, 2010
For some time, the Digest has encouraged the biofuels industry to “Get off the dope,” and dismantle the ineffective web of subsidies and tariffs with which it is ineffectively, expensively, and infamously protected — replacing them with a new schedule of research grants, loan guarantees and mandates that incentivize the production of biofuels that are superior on emissions, environment, and economics.
“Fight an idea with a better idea,” is our motto, and today we present an overview by Digest special correspondent Tim Sklar, “Supporting Biofuels Prices without Taxes or Subsidies,” which examines existing support programs and proposes alternatives which offer a more affordable, equitable means of achieving the transition to renewable fuels.

By Tim Sklar, Biofuels Digest special correspondent
Overview
As addressed in many articles that have appeared in this magazine and in other publications reporting on the renewable energy industry, one of the major impediments to increasing the production and use of biofuels is the difficulty in financing even the most promising of biofuels processing plant projects. Biofuels project developers not only have to find ways to mitigate the technical risks of such projects, and the business risk associated with financing, managing and operating start-up enterprises.
They must often confront the prospect that the biofuels prices they require, may not provide adequate rates of return to their investors. Because biofuels now compete directly against the conventional fuels they are designed to replace, prices received often prove inadequate, as the costs of producing and distributing biofuels are often higher and depend on other factors.
As a consequence, adequate margins over the life of a biofuels project cannot be assured, making many of these projects too risky for obtaining conventional financing.
In the past, government has tried to subsidize biofuels prices, in order to make them comparable to prices being obtained for conventional fuels. In addition, government backed grants; loans and loan guarantees have been offered to biofuels project developers, where conventional financing has not been available.
But in spite of these government initiatives, the prospects for financing biofuels projects remains impaired.
As a consequence there is renewed interest in imposing special taxes on gasoline and other motor fuels and using the tax proceeds to establish and maintain  “trust funds” for financing biofuels project development. There is also renewed interest in using carbon taxes to make it more expensive to use fossil fuels of all types, which proponents believe would increase the prices renewable fuels could command.
Being overlooked are schemes that do not impose new taxes on industry or the individual taxpayer, or create inflationary pressure on the economy. Described in this article is one such scheme that did just that. Known as “The Old Oil Entitlements Program”, this scheme had been used from 1974 to 1981, the period in which price controls had been imposed on refined products sold in the US and on crude oil produced in the US. This scheme  succeeded in equalizing the cost of refined products among US refiners and resellers This article highlights how this was done, how a similar program could be designed to equalize the economic impact on blenders of biofuels, without the use of taxes, subsidies or biofuels floor price mandates.

Blenders’ Tax Credits, An Imperfect Biofuels Price Subsidy

Federal Government incentives that are still being used to encourage the development and use of biofuels are the excise tax credits offered biofuels blenders, a.k.a., and “blenders’ credits”. Biofuels blenders include refiners as well as bulk distributors involved in the “first sale” of transportation fuels, who blend ethanol with gasoline or biodiesel with petroleum diesel. Although these blenders’ credits have had the effect of keeping biofuels prices comparable to prices received for petroleum based transportation fuels, while providing biofuels producers with enough additional revenue to allow them to remain in operation at a time of falling petroleum prices, it appears that blenders’ credits programs will ultimately prove to be inadequate.
First, they do not provide the certainty that adequate biofuels prices can always be obtained. The obvious problem is structural, as the blenders’ credits are set by legislation as a fixed amount per gallon, and subject to change, without regard to changes in fuels market prices.
Second, blenders’ credit legislation that is passed is subject to potential revision, discontinuance or repeal, depending on the prevailing mood in the Congress. And investors in projects that rely on price floors that are propped up by blenders’ credits, have no assurance that these floors would be sustained over the project’s life.
An example of this legislative uncertainty appeared in the May 28, 2010 edition of The Biofuels Digest, in the article titled “US House of Representatives passed the American Jobs and Closing Tax Loopholes Act”. As explained in this article, assuming that this act passes The US Senate, the biodiesel tax credit is to be extended retroactively to January 1, 2010, and expire December 31, 2010. This legislation illustrates provisional nature of biofuels tax credits and the need to obtain continuous political support to insure future biofuels tax credit availability.
Periodically, tax credits of this type become unpopular, as they are viewed as a subsidy to the private sector, paid for by the US taxpayer. Further tax subsidies supporting increased use of “first generation” biofuels, such as corn ethanol, sugar based ethanol and soybean oil derived biodiesel are particularly unpopular with members of Congress who are against USDA programs supporting corn, soybeans and sugar crops.

Gasoline Taxes, A Bad Idea

July’s Car and Driver Magazine had an article that tried to stimulate interest in a gasoline tax to reduce gasoline use and encourage other options such as increased use of biofuels. The author, Aaron Robinson makes reference to a paper published by Harvard’s Dr. Gregory Mankiw in which Dr. Mankiw presents a number of arguments for a higher gasoline tax, making his case based on his economic perspectives. But Dr. Mankiw readily admits that the prospects of imposing higher gasoline taxes remain politically untenable, concluding that the prospects for this option being implemented are remote. Dr Mankiw’s paper can be downloaded from the following website:www.economics.harvard.edu/files/faculty/40_Smart%20Taxes.pdf.

Carbon Taxes, A Controversial Solution

In the European Union, carbon tax regimes are already in place and have undergone adjustments and refinements. The impact on renewable energy producers has been significant, particularly among those who are supplying woody biomass in the form of chips, pellets and torrefied wood to users of coal or natural gas in generating power. In some instances, the price being paid for torrefied wood is in excess of E180 per mt, which is three to four times the price being paid for coal in the US. But if carbon taxes were imposed on coal fired power plants in the US it is argued by opponents of carbon taxes or “cap-n-trade” schemes that the resulting higher cost of fuels will be passed through in the cost of power and ultimately, will add to inflation. And as with the gasoline tax proposals, carbon tax proposal  have proven to be politically untenable, and the prospects for  this option being implemented is also remote and unlikely.

The Old Oil Entitlements Program- Why It Was Necessary

In Phase I of the Economic Stabilization Act of 1970, price ceilings had been initially established on hundred of products and services in most sectors of the US economy. In November, 1971, Phase II commenced, lifting price controls on all sectors other than oil and gas. In January, 1973, Phase III, commenced, making oil and gas price controls voluntary. But heating oil prices spiked and a special rule was passed in March 1973 re-imposing strict price controls on 23 largest domestic refiners, that accounted for 95% of refined product sold.
The rising cost of imported oil forced these refiners to reduce their imports, causing them to reduce product sales to independent marketers and creating product shortages. Congress then passed the Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act in November 1973 creating a two-tiered price control system on domestic oil, namely “Old Oil” and “New Oil”. Old Oil was the oil produced in 1972 from existing wells and was capped at the posted prices in July 1973, which averaged ~$3.50/barrel.
New Oil was domestic oil that was being produced from properties that exceeded base production levels established in 1972. New Oil was allowed to command market prices and it initially averaged between  a ~$8.50 and $11.50 per barrel. Imported oil was never subject to price controls as the US Government had no jurisdiction. Imported oil often commanded prices that exceeded the prices paid for New Oil.
During this period, the price for gasoline in the United States reflected these increased costs, thus allowing refiners who had significant access to Old Oil an opportunity to realize much larger profits than their competitors who did not. This immediately led to market distortions whereby refiners with higher crude oil costs were often not able to realize prices for fuels that their higher costs would allow, and as a consequence, many began to operate at a loss.
How It Worked
FEA then instituted The Old Oil Entitlements Program to equalize the cost of crude oil among refiners. Basically, those refiners who had the advantage of using more Old Oil as a percentage of operations than the industry average, had to buy “entitlements” from those refineries that used less than average percentage amount of Old Oil. In other words, buying “entitlements” allowed refiners to run the excess amounts of Old Oil that they had, but they had to make  money transfers by paying refiners who had less than average amounts of Old Oil and had entitlements to sell.
FEA’s role was to administer this program, by matching buyers of entitlements to entitlements sellers, and overseeing the transfer of funds from buyers to sellers. The price of each entitlement reflected the difference between the system-wide average per barrel price being paid for decontrolled oil and the system-wide average per barrel price being paid for Old Oil. Over its life from 1974 to 1981 this program underwent many modifications to cope with a variety of changes and distortions that ensued.
These details are well documented in a paper titled “Economic Amnesia: The Case against Oil Price Controls…”, by Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren, Cato Institute, Washington, DC.






A New Program Based on An Old One That Worked- Why Not!

Old Oil Entitlement Program Logic

Exhibit 1a contains a hypothetical list of 20 refiners, their daily throughput capacity in MMBPD, average monthly crude oil processed (run to stills), and the average monthly % of old oil run, and the average domestic (price controlled Old Oil) that was processed.


FEA Old Oil Entitlements Program


Monthly Crude Runs
Refiner
Total Old  Oil Old Oil
Number MMBPD Run to Stills % of Total Run to Stills
1 300,000 9,090,000 30% 2,727,000
2 270,000 8,181,000 40% 3,272,400
3 243,000 7,362,900 50% 3,681,450
4 218,700 6,626,610 25% 1,656,653
5 196,830 5,963,949 20% 1,192,790
6 177,147 5,367,554 20% 1,073,511
7 159,432 4,830,799 30% 1,449,240
8 143,489 4,347,719 40% 1,739,088
9 129,140 3,912,947 20% 782,589
10 116,226 3,521,652 10% 352,165
11 104,604 3,169,487 20% 633,897
12 94,143 2,852,538 30% 855,761
13 84,729 2,567,284 40% 1,026,914
14 76,256 2,310,556 50% 1,155,278
15 68,630 2,079,500 40% 831,800
16 61,767 1,871,550 30% 561,465
17 55,591 1,684,395 20% 336,879
18 50,032 1,515,956 10% 151,596
19 45,028 1,364,360 70% 955,052
20 40,526 1,227,924 90% 1,105,132
Totals 2,635,270 79,848,682 32% 25,540,659



Crude Oil Acquisition Costs in $/bbl-1974 8.39



Exhibit 1a


































Exhibit 1b provides entitlements calculations for each of the 20 refiners.
  • Column (a) shows he amount of Old Oil processed and the average monthly price  paid for Old Oil
  • Column(b) shows the amount of Decontrolled Oil   processed and the average monthly price  paid for Decontrolled Oil.
  • Column (c) shows the amount of old oil each refiner would have run if they had acquired the system average of 32% of their runs to stills as Old Oil, and,
  • Column (d) shows the number of entitlements each would have to sell or (buy) and depends on how many barrels of old oil they were short, or they received in excess of the average in which they were entitled.
The row containing information for Refiner # 1 indicates that Refiner #1  received 180,557 fewer barrels of old oil than they were entitled to receive, and would be allowed to sell that number of entitlements to other refiners valued at $28.27/entitlement.
The row containing information for Refiner # 3 indicates that Refiner #3 would have to buy 1,326,329 entitlements from refiners with entitlements to sell.
In other words, Refiner #1 would receive $5,104,346 in revenue from sale of its entitlements and Refiner #3 would have to spend an additional $37,495,316 in order to be able to run its excess old oil.
Further, the $28.27 entitlement price used would have been set for that month by FEA based on the  difference between the $36.66/bbl average decontrolled oil price paid by all participating refiners, and the average old oil price paid of $8.39/bbl.


FEA Old Oil Entitlements Program


a b c d e



Equalized # Entitlements Amount
Refiner Old Oil Oil at Mkt Old Oil @ Avg= to Sell/(Buy) Received or (Paid)
No. Run to Stills Run to Stills 32% Col. c – Col. a Col. d x E’Price
1 2,727,000 6,363,000 2,907,557 180,557 5,104,346
2 3,272,400 4,908,600 2,616,801 -655,599 -18,533,775
3 3,681,450 3,681,450 2,355,121 -1,326,329 -37,495,316
4 1,656,653 4,969,958 2,119,609 462,957 13,087,782
5 1,192,790 4,771,159 1,907,648 714,858 20,209,046
6 1,073,511 4,294,043 1,716,883 643,373 18,188,141
7 1,449,240 3,381,559 1,545,195 95,955 2,712,659
8 1,739,088 2,608,631 1,390,676 -348,412 -9,849,608
9 782,589 3,130,358 1,251,608 469,019 13,259,155
10 352,165 3,169,487 1,126,447 774,282 21,888,950
11 633,897 2,535,590 1,013,802 379,905 10,739,915
12 855,761 1,996,777 912,422 56,661 1,601,798
13 1,026,914 1,540,371 821,180 -205,734 -5,816,095
14 1,155,278 1,155,278 739,062 -416,216 -11,766,427
15 831,800 1,247,700 665,156 -166,644 -4,711,037
16 561,465 1,310,085 598,640 37,175 1,050,940
17 336,879 1,347,516 538,776 201,897 5,707,631
18 151,596 1,364,360 484,899 333,303 9,422,475
19 955,052 409,308 436,409 -518,643 -14,662,051
20 1,105,132 122,792 392,768 -712,364 -20,138,529
Totals 25,540,659 54,308,023 0 0 0
Avg. 8.39 36.66 Entitlement Price 28.27





Exhibit 1b
As can be observed, in Column d, the numbers of entitlements that must be bought and sold zero out, as do the amounts that have to be paid and received. It should be observed that neither the Government, nor the taxpayers were involved in this equalization scheme.









A Program to Equalize Use of Biofuels Costs Among Blenders
Envisioned is the development of a program that uses computational logic that is conceptually similar to the logic used in the Old Oil Entitlements Program. Instead of “equalizing” the proportions of old oil refiners had run, this program would be used to equalize the cost differentials associated with the varying proportions of biofuels blenders actually use. Such a program would require:
a) A biofuels use mandate imposed by the Federal Government on blenders of gasoline and diesel fuel to create a demand for biofuels; and,
b) A biofuels cost equalization program similar to the FEA’s Old Oil Entitlements program that would make those blenders who do not blend the mandated percentage of biofuels into their petroleum fuels products, to pay the added cost they would have incurred for doing so, to those resellers who blend more than the mandated percentage at a higher cost.
This avoids having a tax on consumers while increasing demand for biofuels It also provides an opportunity to biofuels producers for obtaining a higher price, without having to rely on  government subsidies to support a floor price.
In Exhibit 2a, a demonstration of how Old Oil Entitlements logic could be used for equalizing blenders ethanol use in a mandated program. It is assumes that a Federal “mandate” would require the use of 10% ethanol in motor gasoline and the ethanol blending subsidization would “encourage” blending of enough E85 to achieve an average 15% use of ethanol in all motor gasoline blends. In this example, 20 hypothetical blenders were selected, each having blended and sold different quantities of blended motor gasoline, and each having used varying percentages in the gasoline blend, with none less than 10%. And as shown, the average proportion of ethanol used in blending was 14.65%, slightly less than the 15% targeted by this hypothetical ethanol subsidy program.

Exhibit 2a Ethanol Blending Subsidization Program





Avg Gallons/day Monthly Gallons
Bulk Terminal Motor Gasoline Motor Gasoline % of
Gasoline Reseller Produced/Sold Produced/Sold Ethanol Blended
1 6,552,000 198,525,600 10%
2 5,896,800 178,673,040 15%
3 5,307,120 160,805,736 20%
4 4,776,408 144,725,162 10%
5 4,298,767 130,252,646 15%
6 3,868,890 117,227,382 20%
7 3,482,001 105,504,643 10%
8 3,133,801 94,954,179 15%
9 2,820,421 85,458,761 20%
10 2,538,379 76,912,885 10%
11 2,284,541 69,221,597 15%
12 2,056,087 62,299,437 20%
13 1,850,478 56,069,493 10%
14 1,665,430 50,462,544 15%
15 1,498,887 45,416,289 20%
16 1,348,999 40,874,661 10%
17 1,214,099 36,787,194 15%
18 1,092,689 33,108,475 20%
19 983,420 29,797,628 10%
20 885,078 26,817,865 15%
Totals 57,554,298 1,743,895,217 14.6%











In Exhibit 2b, the blending percentages for each blender are applied to the total monthly amount of motor gasoline each produced and sold. Ethanol used is shown under Column (a), and un-blended motor gasoline under Column (b.)
As shown in Column(c), the system-wide average of 14.6% of ethanol blended is applied to total motor gasoline produced by each blender, to arrive at “equalized ethanol gallonage”.
Calculations contained in Columns (d) and (e) reflect the number of entitlements each blender must buy or sell and the amounts that they will pay or receive, based on the recently published average rack prices being paid for ethanol ($4/ gallon) and for unleaded ex. tax gasoline, ($2.16/gal.).
In this example, Blender #1 only blended 10% ethanol and was required to pay an additional $256,785,643 to make up for the 4.6% it did not blend. In contrast, Blender #3 used 20% ethanol in its blended gasoline and was entitled to receive a subsidy of $246,601,445 to offset its added costs.
In addition, a scheme such as this would allow ethanol producers to receive a price that is not directly tied to motor gasoline prices, but would be set by the supply and demand for ethanol.
And if the Government mandates the use of higher ethanol fractions, demand for ethanol would increase and the use of higher cost 2nd generation biofuels such as cellulosic ethanol will become possible, as the market would provide a floor price that is acceptable to those building biofuels plants of this type,
It is expected that the version of an ethanol blending equalization program that is presented, may be too simplistic. If a program similar to the one presented is actually implemented, it is expected that separate biofuels blending equalization programs may be needed for each region of the country. It is well documented that fuel prices vary significantly in regions such as New England, the Central Atlantic, the Lower Atlantic, the Midwest, the Gulf Coast, the Rocky Mountain, and the West Coast and in California. It is also well documented that regional and jurisdictional price differences can be attributed to differences in environmental restrictions, different blending requirements, taxes, transport costs, storage limitations, and seasonal demand patterns, and subsidization should reflect price differentials that normally occur.
Likewise, it is envisioned that similar equalization schemes could be used to support increased use of biodiesel and other biofuels blend stocks, such as butanol and methanol.
Exhibit 2b



Ethanol Blending Subsidization Program


a b c d e
Blender Monthly Gallons Monthly Gallons Equalized # Entitlements Amount
Terminal Ethanol Gasoline Gallons -Ethanol to Buy/(Sell) Paid or (Received)
No. Blended Blended 14.6% Col. c – Col. a Col. d x E’Price
1 19,852,560 178,673,040 28,935,887 9,083,327 256,785,643
2 26,800,956 151,872,084 26,042,298 -758,658 -21,447,264
3 32,161,147 128,644,589 23,438,068 -8,723,079 -246,601,445
4 14,472,516 130,252,646 21,094,261 6,621,745 187,196,733
5 19,537,897 110,714,749 18,984,835 -553,062 -15,635,055
6 23,445,476 93,781,905 17,086,352 -6,359,125 -179,772,454
7 10,550,464 94,954,179 15,377,717 4,827,252 136,466,419
8 14,243,127 80,711,052 13,839,945 -403,182 -11,397,955
9 17,091,752 68,367,009 12,455,950 -4,635,802 -131,054,119
10 7,691,289 69,221,597 11,210,355 3,519,067 99,484,019
11 10,383,239 58,838,357 10,089,320 -293,920 -8,309,109
12 12,459,887 49,839,550 9,080,388 -3,379,500 -95,538,452
13 5,606,949 50,462,544 8,172,349 2,565,400 72,523,850
14 7,569,382 42,893,162 7,355,114 -214,267 -6,057,341
15 9,083,258 36,333,032 6,619,603 -2,463,655 -69,647,532
16 4,087,466 36,787,194 5,957,642 1,870,176 52,869,887
17 5,518,079 31,269,115 5,361,878 -156,201 -4,415,801
18 6,621,695 26,486,780 4,825,690 -1,796,005 -50,773,051
19 2,979,763 26,817,865 4,343,121 1,363,359 38,542,147
20 4,022,680 22,795,185 3,908,809 -113,871 -3,219,119
Totals 254,179,583 1,489,715,634 0 0 0
$/Gal 4.00 2.16 Entitlement Price 1.84
Hopefully, this article makes the case for considering  blending equalization programs similar to the one that has been described as being a most expeditious way to foster increased biofuels production, and worthy of serious consideration by the Biofuels industry participants and the policy makers in the US Government
It should also be obvious, that without programs that are specifically designed to materially stimulate biofuels production and use, there is little hope that there will be enough biofuels  available to  meet the goals that have already been mandated by the Renewable Fuels Standards set by Congress.
Prepared by S. L. Sklar. President,
Sklar & Associates, Biofuels Project Developers

Sklar and Associates
242 Laurel Bay Drive
Murrells Inlet, SC 29576
www.sklarinc.com
Tel:
202/257-5061
sklarincdc@aol.com

Print Friendly

More Coverage on this Topic

Comments (0)

There are no comments yet. Why not be the first to speak your mind.
Comments are closed.



No comments:

Post a Comment